Optimal college application strategy with homogeneous and heterogeneous application costs.
Basic usage:
julia> using OptimalApplication
julia> mkt = SameCostsMarket(
# Probability of getting into each school
[0.2, 0.5, 0.1, 0.6, 0.1],
# Utility values
[1, 4, 9, 1, 8],
# Number of schools `h` to apply to. By nestedness property,
# we can obtain the solution for all `h` by setting `h = m`,
# where `m` is the number of schools in the market.
5
);
julia> x, v = applicationorder_list(mkt)
([2, 3, 5, 4, 1], [2.0, 2.7, 3.24, 3.483, 3.5154])
julia> x[1:4], v[4]
([2, 3, 5, 4], 3.483)
This means that when h = 4
, the optimal portfolio is {2, 3, 5, 4}
and its valuation is 5.408
.
The function applicationorder_heap()
works the same way but uses a different internal data structure and may be faster for certain instances.
Example with varied costs:
julia> mkt = VariedCostsMarket(
# Probability of getting into each school
rand(50),
# Utility values
rand(40:60, 50),
# Cost of applying to each school
rand(5:10, 50),
# Budget to spend on applications
100
);
julia> x, v = optimalportfolio_dynamicprogram(mkt)
([50, 49, 48, 47, 46, 45, 44, 43, 42, 41, 40, 38, 35, 28], 59.66127736008859)
For a large market like this, we may be content with an ε-approximate solution:
julia> x, v = optimalportfolio_fptas(mkt, 0.25)
([26, 46, 50], 59.623041055190996)
The value ε = 0.25
means that the value is guaranteed to be no worse than 1 - 0.25
times the value of the optimal portfolio. As we can see above, the typical optimality gap is often much tighter.
The package also includes optimalportfolio_enumerate()
and optimalportfolio_branchbound()
, which are inefficient algorithms of primarily theoretical interest.
Finally, we can check the expected value of an arbitrary portfolio using valuation()
:
julia> valuation([20, 16, 35], mkt)
35.33785503577366
If you found this package useful, please consider citing our arXiv paper. Rolling updates to the paper can be found on the companion repository CollegeApplication.